Skip to main content
Log in

Effective climate clubs require ambition, leverage and insulation: Theorizing issue linkage in climate change and trade

  • Published:
The Review of International Organizations Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Many proposals advocate linking climate and trade policy to improve climate cooperation. Since climate mitigation is non-excludable, mitigation cannot be enforced through issue-specific reciprocity, but linking mitigation with trade penalties on non-participants could incorporate trade’s enforcement powers into a climate club. However, this perspective has overlooked the relationship between climate policy preferences and existing trade flows. Using a model of issue linkage in climate and trade motivated by findings from the domestic political economy of international trade, I show that the necessary conditions for climate clubs are exacting. Effective climate–trade clubs require members with high levels of climate policy ambition, export leverage over laggards, and insulation from trade retaliation. However, I show that these three attributes do not necessarily co-occur theoretically or empirically. States that support the club’s goals on one dimension may undermine them on another. The findings provide insights into institutional design, climate politics, and the constraints on issue linkage in international cooperation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability statement

The datasets analyzed in this paper can be accessed as follows: (1) Data on bilateral trade flows are collected by UN Comtrade (United Nations, 2022); (2) data on greenhouse gas emissions are collected from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators (World Bank, 2022). Full replication files are available on Harvard Dataverse at https://doi.org/10.7910./DVN/PKHAXG

Notes

  1. For broad overviews, see Falkner (2016); Hovi et al. (2016).

  2. I set the number of states \(I = 150\). This is a model assumption and reflects roughly the number of states in UN climate negotiations. The number of states in the model impacts the results because preferences are drawn from a distribution, large samples will tend to draw more extreme preferences, and the most extreme preferences on trade constrain the club’s design.

  3. I discuss the implications of this assumption at the end of this section.

  4. Appendix materials are available at the journal’s website.

  5. Increasing \(\beta \) will lead the core club members with relatively low climate preferences and relatively high trade exposure to leave the club; decreasing \(\beta \) will lead some additional states to join the club when their climate preferences are near the club’s standard and they trade less with the club than similarly placed peers.

  6. These countries are listed in the supplementary information.

  7. In extensions, I selected climate laggards using external rankings of climate policy and the results are similar.

  8. Note that Canada, China, Germany, Japan, South Korea, and United States are among the biggest emitters and the states with the highest export leverage over other large emitters. I exclude them from core membership of the leverage club.

  9. An alternative measure of leverage could re-weight export exposure by exports as a share of GDP. This would reflect that exports are more significant to some economies. Overall, the correlation between export exposure and exports as a share of GDP is 0.04 for non-club members, so should not affect the results systematically.

References

  • Aggarwal, V. K. (1998). Reconciling multiple institutions: Bargaining, linkages, and nesting (pp. 1–31).

  • Aklin, M. (2016). Re-exploring the trade and environment nexus through the diffusion of pollution. Environmental and Resource Economics, 64(4), 663–682.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aklin, M., & Mildenberger, M. (2020). Prisoners of the wrong dilemma: Why distributive conflict, not collective action, characterizes the politics of climate change. Global Environmental Politics, 20(4), 4–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S. (2003). Environment and Statecraft: The strategy of environmental treaty-making. Oxford University Press.

  • Biermann, F., et al. (2009). The fragmentation of global governance architectures: A framework for analysis. Global Environmental Politics, 9(4), 14–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colgan, J. D., Green, J. F., & Hale, T. N. (2021). Asset revaluation and the existential politics of climate change. International Organization, 75(2), 586–610.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cullenward, D., & Victor, D. G. (2021). Making Climate Policy Work. Polity.

  • Davis, C. (2004). International institutions and issue linkage: Building support for agricultural trade liberalization. American Political Science Review, 98(1), 153–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Depledge, J. (2006). The opposite of learning: Ossification in the climate change regime. Global Environmental Politics, 6(1), 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs, G., Rocke, D., & Barsoom, P. (1998). Managing the evolution of multilateralism. International Organization, 52(2), 397–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckersley, R. (2012). Moving forward in the climate negotiations: Multilateralism or minilateralism? Global Environmental Politics, 12(2), 24–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falkner, R. (2016). A minilateral solution for global climate change? On bargaining efficiency, club benefits, and international legitimacy. Perspectives on Politics, 14(1), 87–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farias, D. B. L., & Roger, C. (2023). Differentiation in environmental treaty making: Measuring provisions and how they reshape the depth-participation dilemma. Global Environmental Politics, 23(1), 117–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, H., & Newman, A. (2019). Weaponized interdependence: How global economic networks shape state coercion. International Security, 44(1), 42–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Genovese, F. (2019). Sectors, pollution, and trade: How industrial interests shape domestic positions on clobal climate agreements. International Studies Quarterly, 63(4), 819–836.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilligan, M. (2004). Is there a broader-deeper trade-off in international multilateral agreements? International Organization, 58(3), 459–484.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, J. F. (2017). The strength of weakness: Pseudo-clubs in the climate regime. Climatic Change, 144(1), 41–52.

    Article  ADS  Google Scholar 

  • Haas, E. B. (1980). Why collaborate? Issue-linkage and international regimes. World Politics, 32(3), 357–405.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hafner-Burton, E. (2005). Trading human rights: How preferential trade agreements influence government repression. International Organization, 59(3), 593–629.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hagen, A., & Schneider, J. (2021). Trade sanctions and the stability of climate coalitions. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 109, 102504.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hale, T. N., Held, D., & Young, K. (2013). Gridlock: Why Global Cooperation is Failing when We Need It Most. Cambridge: Polity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hänsel, M., et al. (2020). Climate economics support for the UN climate targets. Nature Climate Change, 10(8), 781–789.

    Article  ADS  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, K. (2015). International carbon trade and domestic climate politics. Global Environmental Politics, 15(3), 27–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hovi, J., et al. (2016). Climate change mitigation: A role for climate clubs? Palgrave Communications, 2, 16020.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hovi, J., et al. (2019). The club approach: A gateway to effective climate co-operation? British Journal of Political Science, 49(3), 1071–1096.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hovi, J., & Sprinz, D. (2006). The limits of the law of the least ambitious program. Global Environmental Politics, 6(3), 28–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jinnah, S. (2011). Strategic linkages: The evolving role of trade agreements in global environmental governance. The Journal of Environment & Development, 20(2), 191–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keohane, R. O. (1986). Reciprocity in international relations. International Organization, 40(1), 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keohane, R. O., & Victor, D. G. (2016). Cooperation and discord in global climate policy. Nature Climate Change, 6(6), 570–575.

    Article  ADS  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, S. E., & Margalit, Y. (2021). Tariffs as electoral weapons: The political geography of the US-China trade war. International Organization, 75(1), 1–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lupu, Y. (2013). The informative power of treaty commitment: Using the spatial model to address selection effects. American Journal of Political Science, 57(4), 912–925.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mascher, S. (2018). Striving for equivalency across the Alberta, British Columbia, Ontario and Quebec carbon pricing systems: The Pan-Canadian carbon pricing benchmark. Climate Policy, 18(8), 1012–1027.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKibben, H. E. (2016). To link or not to link? Agenda change in international bargaining. British Journal of Political Science, 46(2), 371–393.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meckling, J., & Hughes, L. (2017). Globalizing solar: Global supply chains and trade preferences. International Studies Quarterly, 61(2), 225–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehling, M., et al. (2019). Designing border carbon adjustments for enhanced climate action. American Journal of International Law, 113(3), 433–481.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milewicz, K., et al. (2018). Beyond trade: The expanding scope of the nontrade agenda in trade agreements. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 62(4), 743–773.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morin, J.-F., & Jinnah, S. (2018). The untapped potential of preferential trade agreements for climate governance. Environmental Politics, 27(3), 541–565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. D. (2015). Climate clubs: Overcoming free-riding in international climate policy. American Economic Review, 105(4), 1339–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. D. (2020). The climate club: How to fix a failing global effort. Foreign Affairs, 99(3), 10–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parry, I., Black, S., & Roaf, J. (2021). Proposal for an international carbon price floor among large emitters. IMF Staff Climate Notes.

  • Poast, P. (2013). Issue linkage and international cooperation: An empirical investigation. Conflict Management and Peace Science, 30(3), 286–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robiou du Pont, Y., et al. (2017). Equitable mitigation to achieve the Paris Agreement goals. Nature Climate Change, 7(1), 38–43.

    Article  ADS  Google Scholar 

  • Rowan, S. (2021). Does institutional proliferation undermine cooperation? Theory and evidence from climate change. International Studies Quarterly, 65(2), 461–475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sebenius, J. (1983). Negotiation arithmetic: Adding and subtracting issues and parties. International Organization, 37(2), 281–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tagliapietra, S., & Wolff, G. B. (2021). Form a climate club: United States. European Union and China. Nature, 591(7851), 526–528.

    CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, A. (2009). The rational enforcement of international law: Solving the sanctioners’ dilemma. International Theory, 1(2), 307–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, A., & Verdier, D. (2014). Multilateralism, bilateralism, and regime design. International Studies Quarterly, 58(1), 15–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • United Nations (2022). United Nations Commodity Trade Statistics Database (Comtrade).http://comtrade.un.org

  • Victor, D. G. (2011). Global Warming Gridlock: Creating More Effective Strategies for Protecting the Planet. Cambridge University Press.

  • World Bank (2022). World Development Indicators.https://databank.worldbank.org/source/world-development-indicators

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank Christina Davis, Jessica Green, Yoram Haftel, Thomas Hale, Jon Hovi, Michael Lipson, Jean-Frédéric Morin, Charles Roger, and Alexandra Zeitz, as well as participants at Harvard University’s Climate Pipeline Project Workshop, McGill University’s Centre for International Peace and Security Studies, and the 2022 annual meetings of the International Studies Association and the Political Economy of International Organization for helpful comments on earlier drafts.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sam S. Rowan.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest statement

The author declares no conflicts of interest.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Axel Dreher.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file 1 (zip 6159 KB)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Rowan, S.S. Effective climate clubs require ambition, leverage and insulation: Theorizing issue linkage in climate change and trade. Rev Int Organ (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-024-09535-6

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-024-09535-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation